TechCentralTechCentral
    Facebook Twitter YouTube LinkedIn
    Facebook Twitter LinkedIn YouTube
    TechCentral TechCentral
    NEWSLETTER
    • News

      France’s Canal+ takes MultiChoice stake to 20%

      7 July 2022

      Huge Group to acquire what was Virgin Mobile in South Africa

      6 July 2022

      TechCentral needs your feedback – 2022 reader survey now live

      6 July 2022

      Call for ‘energy emergency’ to end load shedding

      6 July 2022

      What South Africa can learn from India’s IT boom

      6 July 2022
    • World

      Clear signs of trouble ahead for the global tech industry

      7 July 2022

      Elon Musk had twins last year with Shivon Zilis, one of his top execs

      7 July 2022

      China accuses US of ‘technological terrorism’

      6 July 2022

      Apple devices to get ‘Lockdown Mode’ to fight spyware

      6 July 2022

      Scientists at Cern observe three ‘exotic’ new particles

      6 July 2022
    • In-depth

      The bonfire of the NFTs

      5 July 2022

      The NFT party is over

      30 June 2022

      The great crypto crash: the fallout, and what happens next

      22 June 2022

      Goodbye, Internet Explorer – you really won’t be missed

      19 June 2022

      Oracle’s database dominance threatened by rise of cloud-first rivals

      13 June 2022
    • Podcasts

      Demystifying the complexity of AI – fact vs fiction

      6 July 2022

      How your organisation can triage its information security risk

      22 June 2022

      Everything PC S01E06 – ‘Apple Silicon’

      15 June 2022

      The youth might just save us

      15 June 2022

      Everything PC S01E05 – ‘Nvidia: The Green Goblin’

      8 June 2022
    • Opinion

      South Africa can no longer rely on Eskom alone

      4 July 2022

      Has South Africa’s advertising industry lost its way?

      21 June 2022

      Rob Lith: What Icasa’s spectrum auction means for SA companies

      13 June 2022

      A proposed solution to crypto’s stablecoin problem

      19 May 2022

      From spectrum to roads, why fixing SA’s problems is an uphill battle

      19 April 2022
    • Company Hubs
      • 1-grid
      • Altron Document Solutions
      • Amplitude
      • Atvance Intellect
      • Axiz
      • BOATech
      • CallMiner
      • Digital Generation
      • E4
      • ESET
      • Euphoria Telecom
      • IBM
      • Kyocera Document Solutions
      • Microsoft
      • Nutanix
      • One Trust
      • Pinnacle
      • Skybox Security
      • SkyWire
      • Tarsus on Demand
      • Videri Digital
      • Zendesk
    • Sections
      • Banking
      • Broadcasting and Media
      • Cloud computing
      • Consumer electronics
      • Cryptocurrencies
      • Education and skills
      • Energy
      • Fintech
      • Information security
      • Internet and connectivity
      • Internet of Things
      • Investment
      • IT services
      • Motoring and transport
      • Public sector
      • Science
      • Social media
      • Talent and leadership
      • Telecoms
    • Advertise
    TechCentralTechCentral
    Home»Opinion»Graham Friend»In defence of spectrum auctions

    In defence of spectrum auctions

    Graham Friend By Graham Friend19 May 2015
    Facebook Twitter LinkedIn WhatsApp Telegram Email

    Graham-Friend-180Spectrum is a finite, national resource which has enormous value, as has been highlighted in recent spectrum auctions around the world. Across Africa, regulators have an opportunity to realise the benefits of the 800MHz digital dividend and, following the International Telecommunication Union’s World Radiocommunication Conference later this year, they will also be able to benefit from the release of the 700MHz band. However, the extent to which African nations will be able to benefit from this spectrum will be greatly affected by the method of allocation.

    While the use of auctions for allocating spectrum is commonplace in many markets and regarded as best practice, lots of countries in Africa have historically adopted administered or non-market-based approaches. Despite the popularity of these approaches, in opting not to use auctions to allocate new spectrum, regulators in Africa are unable to realise the spectrum’s full value. African regulators should use some form of auction mechanism to maximise the benefits from the allocation of any new spectrum, including the digital dividend.

    The activities of national telecoms regulators are usually shaped by a set of public policy objectives determined by government. While policy objectives vary slightly from country to country, a common objective is to ensure the most economically efficient use of spectrum, which means allocating it to companies that will generate the greatest economic value from it. A well designed and competitive auction ensures that spectrum is allocated on an efficient basis, as the companies with the highest spectrum values will outbid their weaker competitors and win access to it.

    The alternative to an auction is for the regulator to try and “pick the winners”, and award the spectrum to those operators it thinks will maximise the value from it. The approach is akin to the “central planning” of former communist states, and often has similarly disastrous results. The failure of regulators to identify the winners is no surprise, as they are faced with an almost insurmountable asymmetry of information regarding which operator values the spectrum most highly.

    Achieving an efficient allocation of spectrum, however, may not be the only public policy objective, with governments often having a range of goals. Two common additional objectives are: 1) to provide extensive mobile voice and, increasingly, broadband coverage, and 2) to ensure downstream (post-auction) competition to maximise consumer choice and welfare.

    Spectrum auction design has progressed dramatically since the early days of the notoriously inefficient first price, sealed bid auctions, which were once common. Modern spectrum auction design is now capable of addressing, simultaneously, the multiple policy objectives of coverage requirements, downstream competition and economic efficiency, meaning that by choosing to auction, spectrum regulators can ensure that they achieve their public policy objectives.

    Extracting maximum revenues
    If a regulator does not use some form of auction to allocate spectrum then not only does it risk failing to meet public policy objectives, but it may also fail to raise the maximum possible revenue from the sale of a valuable national resource. In the absence of an auction, the regulator will have to determine the price that the mobile operators will have to pay arbitrarily. In theory, a mobile operator will be prepared to pay up to the maximum value it places on the spectrum. Once again, the regulator faces an impossible task of trying to estimate what the maximum value is, due to an asymmetry of information. The only thing a regulator will know with certainty is that if an operator accepts the spectrum at the regulator’s arbitrarily determined price, then the price must be at, or most probably below, the operators’ spectrum value, meaning that the regulator could almost certainly have sold the spectrum for a higher price.

    While in the context of a competitive auction, where maximising economic efficiency and maximising auction revenues are not necessarily aligned, it is reasonable to presume that if the spectrum is awarded to those that value it most highly then, in doing so, the regulator is also maximising government revenues. As the spectrum awards in the US and India certainly demonstrate, auctions undoubtedly have the ability to raise significant amounts of money for the public purse.

    However, the benefits to the public purse from auctioning spectrum are not limited to the revenues generated at auction, as an auction ensures the spectrum is allocated to the operators that will generate the greatest value or profit from the spectrum. An auction therefore also means that the government will maximise tax receipts from the allocation of spectrum, with the result that regulators can be confident that by opting to auction, they are generating the greatest possible revenue from spectrum allocation.

    gavel-640
    Spectrum auctions are completely transparent, objective and significantly less prone to corruption, says the writer

    The amount paid at auction by a mobile operator for spectrum is often referred to as a “sunk cost”, which is a cost that has already been incurred, and which is non-recoverable. Economists argue that sunk costs are irrelevant for future decision making, such as setting prices. Since the sunk cost has already been incurred, it does not matter at what level prices are set, as it will have no bearing on the money that has already been spent. Economists also contest that in a competitive market, what determines price is the marginal cost of providing the incremental unit of the item being sold. Although others argue that firms typically use accounting-based measures of total average cost to set prices, and so sunk costs do have an impact on end user prices, there is limited empirical, or even anecdotal, evidence to suggest that high spectrum prices have led to higher mobile prices. Regulators can therefore use an auction in the confidence that any revenues raised are not likely to distort consumer pricing decisions.

    The same sunk cost argument can also be made for the impact of spectrum auction prices on future investment. When a mobile operator contemplates future network investment, the only consideration is the associated revenues and costs. Economists also typically invoke the assumption of perfect capital markets to further support the view that auction revenues do not impact future investment decisions by reducing the amount of capital available for future investment. The recent history of the financial markets, however, strongly challenges the efficiency of capital markets, although if a regulator is concerned about future investment, then a deferred payment scheme is entirely compatible with auctions, and can alleviate budgetary concerns. Regulators can therefore be confident that the use of auction will not damage incentives for investment.

    Transparency, confidence and investment
    In the past, spectrum and mobile licences were frequently awarded on the basis of beauty parades. Mobile firms would often have to employ a small army of consultants, for extended periods of time, to prepare elaborate and largely fictional “bid books” or business plans, and the operators with the “best” business plans would secure the spectrum. The scoring of the bid books and identification of the winners was extremely time consuming, highly subjective, lacking in transparency and open to corruption, often resulting in the entire award process becoming subject to legal challenge.

    An auction, in contrast, is completely transparent, objective and significantly less prone to corruption. A well designed auction will increase investors’ confidence in the regulator and government and will help reduce regulatory uncertainty. By reducing uncertainty the regulator will de-risk the market, and by lowering the risk profile they will encourage inward investment. An auction will also significantly reduce the risk of legal challenge, and a well-executed auction will enhance the reputation and standing of the regulator.

    A key issue with beauty parades and drawn-out administered processes is that the award procedure can be overtaken by events in the fast-moving mobile telecommunications world. A well designed auction, in contrast, can be executed quickly, which reduces risk and uncertainty, leading to potentially greater auction revenues. The process of conducting an auction can also be considerably less expensive than the use of a lengthy beauty parade. Furthermore, the benefits of the additional revenues raised are likely to more than offset any incremental costs associated with the administration of an auction.

    The use of an appropriately designed and competitive auction will provide regulators in Africa with a wide range of benefits compared to non-market-based mechanisms.

    With the release of the 800MHz digital dividend and World Radiocommunication Conference 2015 just around the corner, it’s therefore vital that African regulators re-evaluate their method of allocating spectrum, in order to fully realise its potential.

    • Graham Friend is an economist and MD of Coleago Consulting, a specialist telecoms strategy consulting firm that advises regulators and operators on issues relating to spectrum, regulation and network strategy
    Coleago Consulting Graham Friend ITU WRC WRC2015
    Share. Facebook Twitter LinkedIn WhatsApp Telegram Email
    Previous ArticleBackspace: ‘Damage control’
    Next Article Heated debate over SA’s nuclear plans

    Related Posts

    South Africa can no longer rely on Eskom alone

    4 July 2022

    Has South Africa’s advertising industry lost its way?

    21 June 2022

    Rob Lith: What Icasa’s spectrum auction means for SA companies

    13 June 2022
    Add A Comment

    Comments are closed.

    Promoted

    Hot Ink certifies and diversifies to maintain competitive printing edge

    5 July 2022

    Increased flexibility with Dell Precision Mobile Workstations

    5 July 2022

    The 5 secrets of customer experience in the cloud era

    5 July 2022
    Opinion

    South Africa can no longer rely on Eskom alone

    4 July 2022

    Has South Africa’s advertising industry lost its way?

    21 June 2022

    Rob Lith: What Icasa’s spectrum auction means for SA companies

    13 June 2022

    Subscribe to Updates

    Get the best South African technology news and analysis delivered to your e-mail inbox every morning.

    © 2009 - 2022 NewsCentral Media

    Type above and press Enter to search. Press Esc to cancel.